HomeModern Central Bank PoliciesCentral banks and equity market distress

Central banks and equity market distress

-

A short Bundesbank paper presents evidence that the Federal Reserve, the ECB, and the Bank of England have long used policy rates to stabilize financial markets in times of distress. This would suggest that implicit ‘central bank puts’ are not new and that central banks’ tendency to stabilize markets in the past has not prevented serious market dislocations.

“Monetary policy and stock market volatility”, Dirk Bleich, Ralf Fendel, and Jan-Christoph Rülke
Discussion Paper Deutsche Bundesbank No 45/2013
http://econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/87722/1/771925875.pdf

The below are excerpts from the paper. Cursive lines and emphasis have been added.

The gist

“This paper… empirically analyzes whether central banks take asset price volatility into account…In contrast to all of the previous studies our study looks simultaneously at the most important central banks [the Bank of England, the Federal Reserve Bank, the Bank of Japan and the European Central Bank] in a unified empirical framework. Our results suggest that the Bank of England, the Federal Reserve Bank and the European Central Bank systematically respond to an increase of the implicit volatility by a decrease in the interest rate. We take our results as strong evidence that central banks use interest rates to stabilize financial markets in periods of financial market stress.”

The debate

“Even before the financial crises 2007-2009 started there has been a heated debate whether or not central banks should respond to asset price developments. Proponents of a ‘leaning against’ approach argue that a central bank is able to (and then also should) actively counteract excessive asset price increases while advocates of the ‘cleaning-up’ approach are convinced that the central bank should rather ‘mop up’ the negative macroeconomic effects after the burst of a bubble.”

The empirical analysis

To estimate the interest rate reaction function [modeling short term rates in dependence of expected inflation, growth, and equity market volatility] we apply monthly data up to December 2009 [thereafter policy rates were almost stable]. The start of the sample period differs among the central banks due to data availability and we use the following short-term interest rates as the central banks’ instruments: European Central Bank (European Overnight Index Average, EONIA since 1999); Federal Reserve Bank (Federal Funds Rate since 1990); Bank of England (Overnight Interbank Rate since 2000); Bank of Japan (Uncollateralized Overnight Call Rate since 2001).”

“To account for the forward-looking nature and to accurately approximate central banks’ information set, we apply inflation and growth expectations which are publicly available in a forecast poll by Consensus Economics…Implied volatilities are calculated in a forward looking manner and, thus, can be interpreted as expected future volatility of the underlying asset. Hence, all variables which enter our central bank reaction function are forward-looking and available to the central bank in real-time.”

“Interestingly, except for the Bank of Japan the coefficients concerning the asset price volatility are significantly negative. The negative albeit insignificant coefficient for the Bank of Japan might be attributed to the zero interest- rate policy. Hence, if asset price volatility or alternatively financial market stress increases major central banks lower their short-term interest rates…More precisely, we document that an increase in the implicit asset price volatility by 10 units yields a decrease in the short-term interest rate by about one percentage point.”

The conclusion

“We conclude that while academics and policy makers still debate central banks already systematically stabilize financial markets using its interest rate policy. This does also include that central banks might respond to financial market stress due to a possible correlation between expected inflation and expected asset price returns meaning that central banks indirectly stabilize financial market by responding to inflation expectations.”

Editor
Editorhttps://research.macrosynergy.com
Ralph Sueppel is managing director for research and trading strategies at Macrosynergy. He has worked in economics and finance since the early 1990s for investment banks, the European Central Bank, and leading hedge funds.